For College level students also useful for University level student
Friday, June 30, 2017
TYPES OF COSTS- Explicit and Implicit Costs - Direct and Indirect Cost - Private Costs versus Social Costs - Relevant Costs and Irrelevant Costs - Economic Costs and Profits - Separate and Common Costs -Fixed cost and Variable cost
TYPES OF COSTS
There are many different types of
costs that a firm may consider relevant for decision-making under varying
situations. The manner in which costs are classified or defined is largely
dependent on the purpose for which the cost data are being outlined.
Explicit and Implicit Costs: The
opportunity cost (or cost of the foregone alternative) of a resource is a cost
in the most basic form. While this particular definition of cost is the
preferred baseline for economists in describing cost, not all costs in
decision-making situations are completely obvious; one of the skills of a good
manager is the ability to uncover hidden costs. For a long time, there has been
a considerable disagreement among the economists and accountants on how costs
should be treated. The reason for the difference of the opinion is that the two
groups want to use the cost data for dissimilar purposes. Traditionally, the
accountants have been primarily connected with collection of historical cost
data for use in reporting a form's financial behavior and position and in
calculating its taxes. The main function
of accountants have been reporting, stewardship and control. They report of
what has happened, present information that will protect the interests of
various shareholders in the firm, and provide standards against which
performance can be judged. All these have indirect relationship to
decision-making. Business economists, on the other hand, have been primarily
concerned with using cost data in decision-making. These purposes call for
different types of cost data and classification.
Traditional accounting data is not
directly suitable for decision-making. While accountants still rely primarily
on historical cost in determining the profit or loss of a firm, economists
prefer to use the opportunity cost baseline concept for this purpose.
The opportunity cost of a resource
can be defined as the value of the resource in its next best use, that is, if
it were not being used for the present purpose. The opportunity cost is the
benefit of using a resource for the next most attractive alternative. For
example, the opportunity cost of a student's doing a full time MBA could be the
income that he would have earned if he had employed his labor resource on a
job, rather that spending them in studying economics, accounting, and so on.
The time cost, in money terms, can be referred to as implicit cost of doing a MBA.
The out-of pocket costs on tuition
and teaching materials are the explicit costs that a student incurs while
pursuing MBA. Thus the total cost of doing a MBA to a student is implicit costs
(opportunity cost) plus the explicit (out-of pocket) costs.
Accountants typically use those
costs that are recorded in their books as representing an actual transfer of
money. These are explicit or nominal costs and after to not represent full
economic costs that should be considered in a given decision. In addition to
explicit costs the business economist uses implicit or imputed cost in evaluation
a decision.
Furthermore, in measuring the cost
of resource in use, the accountant is only concerned with its acquisition cost.
But, for decision-making purposes, we necessarily talk about future costs and
revenues, and therefore, past costs have very little relevance. Also, the
traditional accounting procedure for valuing assets on the balance sheets is
acquisition cost minus depreciation. This faulty as the true current market
value of an asset may differ from its book value.
Direct and Indirect Costs: There are
some costs, which can be directly attributed to production of a given product.
The use of raw material, labor input, and machine time involved in the
production of each unit can be determined. On the other hand, there are certain
costs like stationery and other office and administrative expenses electricity
charges, depreciation of plant and buildings, and other such expenses that
cannot easily and accurately be separated and attributed to individual units of
production, except on arbitrary basis. When referring to the separate costs of
first category accountants call them the direct, or prime costs per unit. The
accountants refer to the joint costs of the second category as indirect or
overhead costs.
Direct and indirect costs are not
exactly synonymous to what economists refer to as variable costs and fixed
costs. The criterion used by the economical to divide cost into either fixed or
variable is whether or not the cost varies with the level of output, whereas
the accountant divides the cost on the basis of whether or not the cost is
separable with respect to the production of individual output units. The
accounting statement often divides the overhead expenses into 'variable
overhead' and 'fixed overhead' categories. If the variable overhead expenses
per unit are added to the direct cost per unit, we arrive at what economists
call as average variable cost.
Private
Costs versus Social Costs: A further distinction that is useful to make
especially in the public sector, is between private and social costs. Private
costs are those that accrue directly to the individuals or firms engaged in
relevant activity. External costs, on the other hand, are passed on to persons
not involved in the activity in any direct way (i.e. they are passed on to society
at large). Consider the case of a manufacturer located on the bank of a river
that dumps the waste into water rather than disposing if of in some other
manner. While the private cost of dumping to the firm is zero, it is definitely
positive to the society. It affects adversely the people located down stream
and incurs higher costs in terms of treating the water chemically for their
use, or to travel long distances to fetch potable water. If these external
costs were included in the production costs of producing firm, a true picture
of real or social costs of the output would be obtained. Ignoring external
costs may lead to an inefficient and undesirable allocation of resources in
society.
Relevant
Costs and Irrelevant Costs: The relevant costs for decision-making purposes
are those costs, which are incurred as a result of the decision under
consideration. The relevant costs are also referred to as the incremental
costs. Costs that have incurred already and costs that will be incurred in the
future regardless of the present decision are irrelevant costs as far as the
current decision problem is concerned.
There
are basically three categories of relevant or incremental costs. These are the
present-period explicit costs, the opportunity costs implicitly involved in the
decision, and the future cost implications that flow from the decision. for
example, direct labor and material costs, and changes in the variable overhead
costs are the natural consequences of a
decision to increase the output level. Also, if there is any expenditure on
capital; equipment incurred as a result of such a decision, is should be
included in full, not withstanding that the equipment may have a useful life
remaining that the equipment may have a useful life remaining after the present
decision has been carried out. Thus, the incremental costs of a decision to
increase the output level will include all present-period explicit costs, which
will be incurred as a consequence of this decision. It will exclude any
present-period explicit cost that will be incurred regardless of the present
decision.
The
opportunity cost of a resource under use, as discussed earlier, becomes a
relevant cost while arriving at the economic profit of the firm. Many decisions
are having implications for future costs, both explicit and implicit. If a firm
expects to incur some costs in the future as a consequence of the present
analysis, such future costs should be included in the present value terms if
known for certain.
Economic Costs
and Profits: Our
earlier discussion of economic costs suggests that economists and accountants
use the term 'profits' differently. Accounting profits are the firm's total
revenue less its economic costs. But economists define profits differently.
Economic profits are the firm's total revenue less its explicit costs (explicit
and implicit, the latter including a normal profit required to retain resources
in a given line of production). Therefore, when an economist says that a firm
is just covering its costs, it is meant that all explicit and implicit costs
are being met, and that, the entrepreneur is receiving a return just large
enough to retain his or her talents in the present line of production. If a
firm's total receipts exceed all its economic costs, the residual accruing to
the entrepreneur is called an economic or pure profit.
Total
Revenue Minus
|
Economic
Cost = Economic Profit
Accounting
Cost = Accounting Profit
|
An economic profit is not a cost,
because by definition it is a return in excess of the normal profit required to
retain the entrepreneur in a particular line of production.
Separate and Common Costs: Costs can
also be classified on the basis of their trace ability. The costs that can be
easily attributed to a product, a division, or a process are called separate
costs, and the rest are called non-separate or common costs. The distinction
between separate and common costs is of particular significance in a
multi-product firm for setting up economic prices for different products.
Fixed and variable Costs: Fixed costs
are those costs, which in total do not vary with changes in output. Fixed costs
are associated with the very existence of a firm's plant and therefore must be
paid even if the firm's level of output is zero. Such costs as interest on
borrowed capital, rental payments, a portion of depreciation charges on
equipment and buildings, and the salaries of top level management and key
personnel are generally fixed costs.
On the other hand, variable costs
are those costs, which increase with the level of output. They include payment
of raw materials, charges on fuel and electricity, wages and salaries of
temporary staff, depreciation charges associated with wear and tear of assets,
and sales commission, etc.
Accounting Cost and Economic Costs, Past Costs Vs. Future Costs, The Variable Cost Curve, The Short Run Total Cost Curve
I.
Accounting Cost and Economic Costs
Economic
costs are
also known as Explicit Costs or expenditure Costs. There are the contractual
payments made by the employer to those factors of production, which do not
belong to the employer himself.
Accounting Costs, The accounting
Costs are also known as the imputed costs or the implicit costs or non-expenditure
costs. They arise in the case of those factors, which are possessed and
supplied by the employer himself. An employer may contribute his own land, his
own capital and even may himself work as the manager of the firm. As such he is
entitled to receive rent on his land interest on the capital contributed by him
and also salary for his work as manager of the firm. All these items should be
included in accounting costs and would be payable by the employer to himself.
The employer would calculate the on the basis of their alternative or
opportunity costs. The depreciation of capital equipment is still another item
in accounting costs. It is not contractual payment to be made by the employer
to same one, but it is to be credited to the depreciation account by the
employer himself.
II.
Past Costs Vs. Future Costs. Sometimes a distinction is made between actual costs and
future costs. Actual costs or historical costs are records of past costs.
Future costs on the other hand are based on forecasts. The costs which are
relevant for most managerial decision-which are generally forward looking are
forecasts of future costs or comparative connectives concerning future income
statements, appraisal of capital expenditure, decisions on new projects and on
expansion programmers and pricing.
Box:
Calculating Total Cost
|
||||
Number of
workers employed
|
Total
output (pairs of running shoes per week)
|
Fixed
cost
(Rs.)
|
Variable
cost
(Rs.)
|
Total
cost (Rs.)
|
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
|
0
7
18
33
46
55
60
63
65
66
66
64
60s
|
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
|
0
300
600
900
1,200
1,500
1,800
2,100
2,400
2,700
3,000
3,300
3,600
|
500
800
1,100
1,400
1.700
2,000
2,300
2,600
2,900
3,200
3,500
3,800
4,100
|
The
production of shoes is assumed to depend on only two factors of production:
Capital and Labor. Cost of capital is fixed at Rs. 500 per week. Labor can be
hired at Rs. 300 per week. Therefore, the variable cost depends on the number
of workers employed. Total cost is equal to Fixed cost + variable cost. Total
output reflects the law of diminishing returns to labor.
|
Box: The Variable Cost Curve
|
The shape of
the variable cost curve reflects the law of diminishing marginal returns.
When labor is the only variable input in a plant, variable cost is equal to
the number of workers hired per week multiplied by the weekly wage.
|
Box: The Short Run Total Cost Curve
|
The total
cost is the sum of fixed cost and variable cost. Because fixed cost does not
vary with output, the shape of the total cost curves reflects the shape of
the variable cost curve drawn in the pervious box.
|
RELATION BETWEEN PRODUCTION AND COST Money, Real and Opportunity Costs, Fixed Cost and Variable Costs, Explicit Costs and Implicit Costs, Accounting costs and Economic Costs, Past Cost and Future Cost
RELATION BETWEEN PRODUCTION AND COST
The economists frequently assumes
that the problem of optimum input combinations has been solved and conducts his
analysis of the firm in terms of its revenues and costs expressed as functions
of output. The cost function of the firm gives the functional relationship
between total cost and total output. If C represents total cost and Q
represents the level of the output, then the cost functions is represented as
C=C (Q). The same level of output can be produced with the help of different
cost combinations. The cost function gives the least cost combinations for the
production of different levels of output.
Cost functions are derived
functions. They are derived from the production functions, which describes the
available efficient methods of production at any particular point of time. The
cost function can be deduced from the inputs combinations of the firm. The
input prices of the two inputs of production labor (L) and capital (K) are
given to be constant as the wage rate (w) and rent (r), respectively. If L and
K are the amounts of the two inputs that are used for the production of the
output level Q, the firm will always select those combinations of the two
inputs, which lie on the expansion path. Along any expansion path the level of
output increases as we gradually depart from the origin. Within the
non-inferior zone of the factors of production, their total employment will
also increase as we move along the expansion path. Therefore we can say that
along any expansion path the demand for any factor of production will depend on
the level of output to be produced. So, if L and K are the amounts of the
factors of production and Q is the level of output then it can be said that L
and K are functions of Q.
That is,
L = g1(Q)
And, K
= g2(Q)
Now, following the equation of the
costs line, the total cost (C) for producing the output level Q is given by
C = L. w + K.r
or C = w. g1(Q) + r. g2(Q)
or C = C(Q).
Since, w and r are constant C is
only a function of Q. This function is called the total cost functions of the
firm. The function shows that the total cost of the firm depends on the output
to be produced. The costs function is deduced from the expansion path of the
firm.
The cost function derived from the
expansion path of the firm represents the cost function in its long run nature
as in this case we have assumed that both the factors of production are
variable.
A firm's cost curves are linked to its
product curves. Overt the range of rising marginal product marginal; cost if
falling. When marginal product is a maximum, marginal; cost is a minimum. Over
the rang4e of rising average product, average variable cost is falling. When
average product is a maximum, average variable cost is a minimum. Over the range
of diminishing marginal product, marginal cost is rising. And over the range of
diminishing marginal product, average variable cost is rising.
Source:
Addison-Wesley, Economics, 1997, 236
Cost Revenue Analysis and Market
Price determination analysis is based
on the demand and supply forces. These in turn depend on the revenue and the
cost of production respectively. Thus cost and revenue analysis is
indispensable. This analysis exhibit only the profits or losses earned by the
firm but also helps in output determination and production planning.
Distinguish between
i. Money, Real and Opportunity Costs.
ii. Fixed Cost and Variable Costs.
iii. Explicit Costs and Implicit Costs.
iv. Accounting costs and Economic Costs.
v. Past Cost and Future Cost.
And others
i.
Money, Real and Opportunity Costs
Money
costs mean
the aggregate money expenditure incurred by a firm on the various items
entering into the production of a commodity. Money costs relate to money
expenditure by a firm on factors of production, on wages and salaries paid to
labor, on machinery and equipment, for rent and insurance and payment to the
Government by way of taxes.
Real
costs of production is expressed not in money
but in efforts of workers and sacrifices of capitalists undergone in the making
of a commodity. According to Marshall,
it is, "The extent ions of all the different kinds of labor that are
directly and indirectly involved in making it, together with the abstinences or
rather the waiting required for saving the capital used in making it, all these
efforts and sacrifice together will be called the real cost of production of
that commodity, "Marshall had in mind the disability, pain and the
discomfort involved for labor when it is engaged in production and also of the
unpleasantness involved in saving and capital accumulation. The concept of real
cost though of some importance lacks precision since it is expressed in
subjective terms.
Opportunity
Cost. A
person cannot satisfy all his wants since the money at his disposal is limited
in supply. He has to choose between on thing and another. The satisfaction of
one want involves the sacrifice of another. The cost of production of any unit
of a commodity A is the value of the factors of production used in producing
that unit. The value of these factors of production is measured by the best
alternative use to which they might have been put, had a unit of A not been
produced. In other words, the cost of any factor in the production of a
particular good is the maximum amount which the factor unit could yield in the
production of other goods since the firm has to pay to owners of factor units
what these units can secure in alternative occupations, the costs are known as
alternative or alternative or opportunity costs.
The concept of opportunity cost is
applicable to the determination of value in internal and international trade.
But the main drawback of this concept in that is applicable to a specific
factor, that is which can be put to one single use. Since the factor is a
single use factor. It can have no alternative or opportunity cost. The
opportunity cost stands for the cost of producing one unit of a commodity in
terms of another that can be produced instead.
Least-cost combination of Production
Least-Cost Combination
The
problem of least-cost combination of factors refers to a firm getting the
largest volume of output from a given cost outlay on factors when they are
combined in an optimum manner.
In
the theory of production, a producer will be in equilibrium when, given the
cost-price function, he maximizes his profits on the basis of the least-cost
combination of factor. For this he will choose that combination of factors
which maximizes his cost of production. This will be the optimum combination
for him.
Assumptions
The
assumptions on which this analysis is based are:
1. There are two factors. Capital and labor.
2. All units of capital and labor are homogeneous.
3. The prices of factors of production are given and constant.
4. Money outlay at any time is also given.
5. Perfect competition is prevailing in the factor market.
On the basis of given prices of
factors of production and given money outlay we draw a line A, B.
The firm cannot choose and neither
combination beyond line AB nor will it chooses any combination below this line.
AB is known as the factor price line or cost outlay line or iso-cost line. It
is an iso-cost line because it represents various combinations of inputs that
may be purchased for the given amount of money allotted. The slope of AB shows
the price ratio of capital and labour, i.e.,
By combining the isoquants and the factor-price line, we can find out the
optimum combination of factors. Fig. illustrates this point.
In the Fig. equal product curves IQ1,
IQ2 and IQ3 represent outputs of 1,000 units, 2,000 units
and 3,000 units respectively. AB is the factor-price line. At point E the
factor-price line is tangent to iso-quant IQ2 representing 2,000
units of output. Iso-qunat IQ3 falls outside the factor-price line
AB and, therefore, cannot be chosen by the firm. On the other hand, iso-quant
IQ, will not be preferred by the firm even though between R and S it falls with
in the factor-price line. Points R and S are not suitable because output can be
increased without increasing additional cost by the selection of a more
appropriate input combination. Point E, therefore, is the ideal combination
which maximizes output or minimizes cost per units: it is the point at which
the firm is in equilibrium.
What does the point of tangency tell
us? At that point the slope of the factor-price line AB and the slope of the
iso-quant IQ2 are equal. The slope of the factor-price line reflects
the ratio of prices of the two factors. Viz, capital and labour. The slope of
the iso-quant reflects the marginal rate of technical substitution. At point E
the ratio of prices of capital and labour is equal to the marginal rate of
technical substitution. The condition of optimal combination is, therefore,
given by the equality of the ratio of prices between any two factors and the
rate of technical substitution between them. This is the point at which and
firm is able to produce maximum quantity and at minimum cost.
Every firm, interested in maximising
output or minimising cost, must therefore, consider (a) factor-price ratio
which tells the firm the rate at which it can substitute one factor for another
in purchasing, and (d) the marginal rate of technical substitution which tells
the firm the rate at which it can substitute one factor for another in
production. So long as the two are not equal, a firm can achieve a greater output
or a lower cost by moving in the direction of equality.
Possibility of Operation of Production
Possibility of operation
The law of variable proportions
guides us about the possibility of operation. A rational producer will never
choose first and third stage for its production he will always operate in the
second stage, i.e. the stage of diminishing returns. The producer will not
produce in the first and the third stages because in the first stage the fixed
factor of production i.e. capital is underutilized and its marginal return is
negative and in third stage the variable factor of production i.e. labor is
over utilized and thus its marginal return becomes negative. In other words,
the marginal return of fixed factor and variable factor is negative in first
stage and third stage respective. It is the second stage where the return on
both the fixed factors and variables though diminishing is positive. The
producer will always produce in second stage.
Returns to Scale Meaning
In the run all factors are variable,
hence the expansion of output may be achieved by varying all factor-inputs.
When we change all factor-inputs in the same proportion, the scale of
production is also changed. The study of the effect of change in the scale of
production on the amount of output comes under the head of returns to scale.
Thus, the term returns to scale
refers to the changes in output as all factor-inputs change by the same
proportion in the long run.
Or, in other words, the law
expressing the relations between varying scales of production and quantities of
output is called returns to scale. In short, returns to scale refer to the
effects of scale relationship.
Three Types
Now the question is at what rate the
output will increase when all factor- inputs are varied in the same proportion.
There can be three possibilities in this regard. The increase in output may be
more than, equal to, or less than proportional to the increase in
factor-inputs. Accordingly, returns to scale are also of three types-increasing
returns to scale, constant returns to scale and diminishing returns to scale.
S.N.
|
Returns
to a Variable Factor
|
Returns
to Scale
|
1
|
Operates
in the short run
|
Operates
in the long run.
|
2
|
Only
the Quantities of factor are varied
|
All
factor-inputs are varied in the same proportion
|
3
|
Changes
in the factor-ratio.
|
No
change in the factor-ratio
|
4
|
No
change in the scale of production
|
Changes
in the scale of production.
|
Three Stages of Productions
THE
THREE STAGES OF PRODUCTION
According to Cassels, there
are three stages in the production process, when we vary one factor of
production, the other factor remaining the same. In stage I, there is
increasing average returns to the factor of production, i.e. > 0
i.e. MPL
> APL. In stage I, the average product is increasing and the
marginal product is greater than the average product. If we refer to figure 4.3
we see that up to the point B on the TP curve, stage I exists. In stage I AP is
increasing but MP is first increasing up to A and then decreasing. In stage II,
the average product is decreasing and the marginal product is also decreasing,
but marginal product is positive. This stage may be called the stage of
decreasing returns. The portion of the total product curve between B and C
represents this stage. In stage III, total product is diminishing and the
marginal product is negative. This stage is called the stage of negative
returns. The portion of the total product curve, which lies to the right of the
point C, represents this stage.
Let us now discuss the rationale
behind the operation of the three stages of production. In the beginning the
quantity of the fixed factor of production (which is capital in our case) is
abundant relative to the variable factor of production, i.e. labor. Therefore,
when more and more units of the variable factor is used, the fixed factor is
used more intensively and efficiently. This causes the production to increase
at a rapid rate implying increasing AP and MP. But once the point A is reached
where the variable factor is used at such a rate that ensures the efficient
utilization of the fixed factor, any further increase in the variable factor
will cause MP and AP to fall because the quantity of the fixed factor has now
become limiting compared to the amount of the variable factor. Again in the
stage III the quantity of the variable factor is so large compared to the fixed
factor that the formed comes in each other's way, thereby reducing the
efficiency of the fixed factor, which results in a fall in the total product
instead of rising. This is the reason behind the negativity of the marginal
productivity in this stage. Comparing stage I and stage III, it can be said
that, stage III is the mirror image of stage I.
Now the question, which immediately
comes in our mind, is that, in which stage would the rational entrepreneur like
to be? The answer is the rational entrepreneur will always like to operate in
stage II of the production function. Let us analyze the reason behind this.
In stage I, MP and AP both are
rising, and MP is more than AP. This has two implications:
i.
A
given increase in the variable factor leads to a more than proportionate
increase in the output.
ii.
The
entrepreneur is not making the best possible use of the fixed factor.
In this case the entrepreneur will
employ more of the variable factor keeping the fixed factor constant, i.e. a
particular portion of the fixed factor remains unutilized.
Considering the stage III we will
see that the MP of the variable factor is negative and the TP is also
decreasing. Hence the national entrepreneur will not operate in this stage.
However,
if we consider stage II, we find that MP and AP are both falling and MP, though
positive, is less than AP. Moreover, at this stage, there is less than
proportionate change in output due to change in labor. Hence, at this stage the
entrepreneur will employ the variable factor in such a manner that the
utilization of the fixed factor is most efficient. So this is the stage in
which the entrepreneur can use both of the available resources in an optional
manner.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)
TYPES OF MICRO ECONOMICS
The analysis of microeconomics is always affected by time period. But there are still some economists who do not believe the time value...
-
3. TYPES OF MICRO ECONOMICS The analysis of microeconomics is always affected by time period. But there are still some economists who do...